Plan Design Progression Leading to Higher Retirement Savings
Participation rates were nearly 96% higher for plans—a difference of 40 percentage points—with auto enrollment; the usage of auto escalation was nearly five times higher in plans that employ opt-out options rather than opt-in, and employer match rates increased in 2018, T. Rowe Price found.
T. Rowe Price has released its annual participant data benchmarking report, Reference Point, which shows mixed results for participants in 2018. On the positive side, average deferral rates reached a 10-year high of 8.6%, outstanding 401(k) loans fell to a nine-year low of 22.5% and hardship withdrawals fell for the ninth year in a row, from 1.9% in 2010 to 1.3% in 2018.
Participation rates were nearly 96% higher for plans—a difference of 40 percentage points—with auto enrollment (85.6% versus 43.7%), and the usage of auto escalation was nearly five times higher in plans that employ opt-out options rather than opt-in (67% versus 12%). Nearly 37% of plans with automatic enrollment use a default deferral rate of 6%, while 33% use a default rate of 3%.
Employer match rates increased in 2018, with more offering a match of 4% than 3% for the first time. The reduction of the corporate tax rates most likely contributed to the increase in company matches in 2018, T. Rowe Price says.
The adoption of target-date products reached an all-time high of 95%, and the percentage of participants with their entire balance invested in a target-date product has grown by 20% since 2014. Nearly 75% of plans now offer a Roth option, and the number of participants making Roth contributions increased by nearly 10% from the year before. However, overall usage remains at a low 7.6%.
On the negative side, the participation rate dropped by nearly two percentage points from the year prior, and plans without automatic enrollment saw participation drop at more than twice the rate than those with auto enrollment. “It’s a sign that auto-solutions can help mitigate macro forces that may be decreasing participation rates,” T. Rowe Price says in its report. This is particularly true of younger participants, with 80% of those between the ages of 20 and 69 remaining in plans with automatic enrollment, compared with only 25% of this age group deciding to join a plan without automatic enrollment on their own.
Participants who saved less in 2018 decreased their deferral rates by a greater amount than those who increased their deferral rates.
The percentage of participants contributing 0% increased to 36%, an increase of five percentage points from 2017, and average account balances decreased by nearly 8% (from $92.402 to $85,336), in part because of the year-end market correction. This volatility also prompted participants to move out of equities into more conservative investments—with stock holdings ticking down from 34.8% of the average portfolio in 2017 to $33.1 in 2018 and stable value holdings rising from 8.9% to 9.8%. Furthermore, there was a 36% increase in cash-out distributions in 2018 to 26% of participants taking a cash-out, which T. Rowe Price says could have been caused by participants’ uncertainty about the markets and movement from accounts with small balances.
“Non-contributors may benefit from additional education about plan benefits, including company match, if applicable,” T. Rowe Price says.
While outstanding loans fell in 2018, the average loan balance rose from $9,194 the year before to $9,351. Likewise, the average hardship withdrawal increased to $7,080, up slightly from 2017 and up from the 10-year low of $5,628 in 2009.
“Overall, we’ve seen an increase in positive participant behavior,” says Kevin Collins, head of retirement plan services at T. Rowe Price. “However, there are still opportunities for continued improvement. Plan sponsors can provide this support through plan design and by integrating financial wellness programs into their plan offering.”
T. Rowe Price’s findings are based on an analysis of the 657 401(k) and 457 plans and the 1.8 million participants that the firm serves. The full Reference Point report can be downloaded here.
Michael Barry, president of O3 Plan Advisory Services LLC, discusses the inconsistencies in the Department of Labor’s (DOL)’s theory of retirement plan sponsor fiduciary responsibility, especially with respect to participant choice, and the consequences of its failure to provide clear guidance.
Why exactly does the Department of Labor (DOL) believe the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) prudence rule exists? The intuitive answer to this question, based on traditional fiduciary theory, would be that when a participant sets aside savings for retirement an “other people’s money” problem is created. Individuals (fiduciaries) are investing on behalf of others (participants). Which creates an agency problem. And the law solves that problem by imposing a high standard of care on the investment manager/fiduciary.
That policy concern may be extended to a participant-directed account plan where, unlike an individual, non-plan investor, the participant only has access to a limited menu of funds to choose from, “curated” by plan fiduciaries. It would, however, not be implicated where the participant has (e.g., via a brokerage window) access to—may invest her savings in—something approximating the entire market—that is, where the participant can direct her investment more or less as she would if she were saving outside the employer plan system (and outside DOL’s jurisdiction).
In its famous (and ultimately vacated) fiduciary rule, as grounds for its (unprecedented) assertion of jurisdiction over IRAs, DOL articulated a different, novel and, as the head of DOL’s Employee Benefits Security Administration (EBSA) described it, “creative” theory:
The specific duties imposed on fiduciaries by ERISA and the Code stem from legislative judgments on the best way to protect the public interest intax-preferredbenefit arrangements that are critical to workers’ financial and physical health. [Emphasis added.]
So, the fiduciary rules don’t (or at least don’t just) protect the participant. They protect “the public interest,” for which DOL speaks. And, quite aside from the traditional fiduciary concern about agency, our tax policy gives DOL the right to insert itself into investment decisions of the participant.
In addition to providing a pretext for its application of ERISA’s general fiduciary rules to IRAs—the investment of which is generally entirely under the control of the IRA owner—this theory also provides a rationale for DOL’s prohibition (in FAB 2018-01) of investment in “bad” ESG (environmental, social and governance) funds, that is, ESG funds that cannot be justified on strictly economic grounds. Even where the participant, after full disclosure, wants to make the investment.
This theory begins to fray at the edges when we consider DOL’s position on brokerage windows. It’s fair to say that most practitioners believe that, where, e.g., an investment “platform” (e.g., a brokerage window) offers (literally) thousands of different mutual funds, the fiduciary prudence obligations that apply to a plan’s “core” investment funds don’t apply to the funds in the brokerage window. For one thing, plan fiduciaries generally have no control over which funds are/are not offered in the window. For another, there are so many funds offered, the idea that an ERISA fiduciary could select and monitor each one for performance or reasonableness of fees, in a way that conforms to ERISA’s prudence standard, is kind of ludicrous. And who, exactly would that fiduciary be? Certainly not the window provider.
DOL, however, can’t stand the idea of an employer/sponsor somehow getting off the fiduciary-responsibility hook by simply offering participants the opportunity to invest in the market (via a brokerage window) the way any other investor could. And so, in the revised version of FAB 2012-02 Q&A 39 DOL stated:
[I]n the case of a 401(k) or other individual account plan covered under the [participant disclosure] regulation, a plan fiduciary’s failure to designate investment alternatives, for example, to avoid investment disclosures under the regulation, raises questions under ERISA section 404(a)’s general statutory fiduciary duties of prudence and loyalty.
So, in DOL’s view, you can’t have a “window only” plan. ERISA’s prudence obligation requires that the “plan fiduciary” designate (in effect, curate) a core fund menu. Why? The only possible theory is the one that we just discussed—“protecting the public interest in a tax-preferred benefit.” Is there anything in ERISA that actually says that?
We turn next to plaintiffs’ contention that Deere violated its fiduciary duty by selecting investment options with excessive fees. In our view, the undisputed facts leave no room for doubt that the Deere Plans offered a sufficient mix of investments for their participants. Thus, even if, as plaintiffs urge, there is a fiduciary duty on the part of a company offering a plan to furnish an acceptable array of investment vehicles, no rational trier of fact could find, on the basis of the facts alleged in this Complaint, that Deere failed to satisfy that duty. As the district court pointed out, there was a wide range of expense ratios among the twenty Fidelity mutual funds and the 2,500 other funds available through [Fidelity’s] BrokerageLink. At the low end, the expense ratio was .07%; at the high end, it was just over 1%. Importantly, all of these funds were also offered to investors in the general public, and so the expense ratios necessarily were set against the backdrop of market competition.
This language—which seems to say that if you give participants enough choice you are off the hook if they pick funds with high fees—so disturbed DOL that it filed an amicus curiae brief for rehearing en banc. In denying that petition, the 7th Circuit’s Hecker v. Deere three-judge panel disavowed such a reading, stating:
The Secretary also fears that our opinion could be read as a sweeping statement that any Plan fiduciary can insulate itself from liability by the simple expedient of including a very large number of investment alternatives in its portfolio and then shifting to the participants the responsibility for choosing among them. She is right to criticize such a strategy. It could result in the inclusion of many investment alternatives that a responsible fiduciary should exclude. It also would place an unreasonable burden on unsophisticated plan participants who do not have the resources to pre-screen investment alternatives. The panel’s opinion, however, was not intended to give a green light to such “obvious, even reckless, imprudence in the selection of investments” (as the Secretary puts it in her brief).
That reads like an endorsement of DOL’s position, that ERISA plan fiduciaries have a duty (to me at least the source of this duty remains obscure) to curate a fund menu. In fact that language reads like, even if the plan fiduciary has curated a blue-chip best practices totally prudent fund menu, if there is an over-priced, “unsound” or “reckless” fund in the brokerage window, the plan fiduciary is also responsible for that.
I could be wrong here, but I don’t think that any practitioner out there believes that plan fiduciaries have an obligation to scrutinize for prudence the funds in a brokerage window. How could they? It’s my understanding that in some plans, brokerage windows sometimes include a higher fee version of a fund available at a lower fee in the plan’s core fund menu. Investment in that higher fee fund—say, by an “unsophisticated plan participant”—doesn’t seem prudent.
More pertinent to the sorts of issues that providers and sponsors are currently grappling with, most believe that including an ESG fund—even a “bad”one, under FAB 2018-01’s “good vs. bad” criteria—in brokerage windows is “OK”—or at least that it presents significantly less risk than putting that fund in the core fund menu.
But how does that result “protect the public interest in a tax-preferred benefit”—when you can’t invest in a “bad” ESG fund in the core fund menu but you can in the brokerage window?
If the point here isn’t clear, these issues would not be a problem under the alternative (and less creative) theory that ERISA’s prudence requirement is simply solving a (relatively ancient) agency problem. If a participant—after full disclosure and assuming no self-dealing (between the plan and the participant)—wants to invest in a “bad” ESG fund, or in a fund with irrationally high fees, that is not an ERISA problem. Because it’s his money.
That is in fact—despite what DOL claims—what ERISA section 404(c) says in so many words:
In the case of a pension plan which provides for individual accounts and permits a participant or beneficiary to exercise control over the assets in his account, if a participant or beneficiary exercises control over the assets in his account … (i) such participant or beneficiary shall not be deemed to be a fiduciary by reason of such exercise, and (ii) no person who is otherwise a fiduciary shall be liable under this part for any loss, or by reason of any breach, which results from such participant’s or beneficiary’s exercise of control ….
Why does any of this matter? It sounds pretty theoretical. In my experience, however, bad (that is, incoherent) theory is going to produce really bad results. Here—with respect to this one problem I’ve been discussing—is my list of the problems that this theory has created:
Making small plan sponsors function as fiduciaries when they are totally incapable of doing so and don’t have the capacity/money/time to learn how to. And that problem is a big chunk of why small employers don’t have plans. We should just let them have a “window only” plan—and treat them as mere consumers, which is what they are.
Creating the 401(k) fee fiduciary lawsuit industry, which is based (in large part) on seizing on marginal differences in fees, based on cherry picked surveys of the entire fund universe. This industry feeds on the uncertainty around what exactly the standards for a plan fiduciary are. For all I know, DOL thinks all these lawsuits are a good idea (it’s mostly lawyers at DOL, after all). Which is both naïve and sad.
Sending all of us—providers, sponsors, policymakers—on the wild goose chase that was the fiduciary rule, and specifically the attempt by DOL to assert jurisdiction over IRAs. As almost everyone on the other side of this exercise pointed out, in many cases there’s not a lot of difference between a client’s money in an ordinary (and unprotected by ERISA) brokerage account and an IRA.
None of this has been good for the U.S. retirement system. IMHO.
I’m not, in fact, suggesting that DOL abandon its theory. If there are virtues to it I am somehow missing, then go for it. But, then, apply it consistently. Or come up with a version that can be applied consistently.
To repeat what I’ve said in the past, DOL’s conduct here—in not giving clear and coherent guidance on these issues—is an example of what Jeremy Bentham called “dog law”—“When your dog does anything you want to break him of, you wait till he does it, and then beat him for it.”
So—in the absence of clear direction—plan sponsors do their best. And then are judged on DOL’s secret notion of what they should have done, or on what some judge can be talked into believing by the plaintiffs lawyer industry. Then, having been beaten like dogs, plan fiduciaries—who were and are generally only trying to do the right thing—conform to whatever sense they can make out of the new (generally obscure and incoherent) rule that has been explained to them via a money judgment.
Michael Barry is president of O3 Plan Advisory Services LLC, and author of the new book, “Retirement Savings Policy: Past, Present, and Future.” He has 40 years’ experience in the benefits field, in law and consulting firms, and blogs regularly http://moneyvstime.com/ about retirement plan and policy issues.
This feature is to provide general information only, does not constitute legal or tax advice, and cannot be used or substituted for legal or tax advice. Any opinions of the author do not necessarily reflect the stance of Institutional Shareholder Services (ISS) or its affiliates.