Wells Fargo Names Head of Retirement Benefits Consulting
February 27, 2014 (PLANSPONSOR.com) – Wells Fargo Retirement has named Betsy Hammond as head of its Nashville-based retirement benefits consulting division.
Hammond will report to Joe Ready, director of Wells Fargo
Institutional Retirement and Trust.
“Over the years, clients have benefited from the expertise
and knowledge that Betsy Hammond and her team delivers consistently day in and
day out,” says Ready. “She is well-regarded both within the organization and
the industry overall. In her new role as head of benefits consulting, she will
continue her rich tradition of excellence and track record of outstanding performance
as she leads this team.”
Hammond joined Wells Fargo’s retirement benefits consulting
group in 1992 as an actuarial analyst, the firm says. She later moved into a variety of
leadership roles and was named a principal of the benefits consulting business in
1999. Since 2004, Hammond has been director of actuarial services, managing a
team of 46 professionals who deliver benefits consulting expertise to clients.
She has overseen the firm’s actuarial student exam and training program and
helped drive the development of Wells Fargo’s defined benefit administration
product.
Hammond graduated with a bachelor’s degree in
economics from Davidson College and a master’s degree in actuarial science from
Georgia State. She achieved her enrolled actuary designation in 1997, a fellow designation from the Society of Actuaries in 1998, and a fellow designation from the Conference of
Consulting Actuaries in 2005.
Brookings Gets Ball Rolling for Public Pension Policy Discussions
February 27, 2014 (PLANSPONSOR.com) – During a discussion at The Brookings Institution in Washington, D.C., speakers discussed a framework and political process for pension reform policies.
The
Brown Center on Education Policy at Brookings released two papers that
examine pension reform efforts across the nation and provide actionable policy
solutions aimed at those states still struggling with underfunded pension
systems. Patten Priestley Mahler, economics Ph.D. candidate at the University
of Virginia, told event attendees that “Improving Public Pensions, Balancing
Competing Priorities” offers a framework for evaluating reforms and discusses
a pension plan that meets these goals. “It’s not a silver bullet, but it shows how
workers’ and taxpayers’ competing interests can be met,” she says.
According
to Mahler, the paper establishes three goals for pension reform. The first goal—to provide sufficient retirement security—is better met by defined benefit (DB) plans, she
contends, because DBs do a good job of protecting participants from market risk,
while defined contribution (DC) plans subject participants to market risk.
However, she adds, it could be argued DBs are only better for long-term
employees.
With
the second goal—to maintain fiscal sustainability—DBs have an issue with
governmental accountability, Mahler notes. Governments can skip payments; and
the costs of DBs are complex, not transparent. DCs do not have these issues.
For
the third goal—to maintain public employee productivity—it is uncertain which type of plan is better. Both DBs and DCs have pros and cons for
encouraging productivity, she says.
The report—written
by Mahler; Matthew M. Chingos, a fellow in the Brown Center on Education Policy
at the Brookings Institution; and Grover J. “Russ” Whitehurst, director
of the Brown Center—outlines a “collective” defined contribution plan that
combines the strengths of a DC plan with the advantages of risk pooling and
shared investment management, to strike a balance toward attaining the goals
above.
Similar
to other DC plans, a collective DC provides each individual a retirement
savings account where employer and employee contributions and investment
accruals are held. Distinct from DC plans, all accounts are managed
collectively, meaning that the plan provider chooses how money is invested, as well as how and when investment returns are divvied among plan members. A collective DC
plan capitalizes on risk pooling to lessen the risk borne by individuals
without increasing the risk to employers.
Mahler
says a nationwide public sector plan could help mobile workers as they move
between states and across the country.
However,
political barriers to implementing public pension reform are high, according to
Patrick McGuinn, associate professor and chair of the Department of Political
Science at Drew University. In another paper, “Pension Politics: Public
Employee Retirement System Reform in Four States,” McGuinn provides an overview
of the political dynamics around pension reform nationwide, as well as comparative
case studies of reform efforts in four states with diverse political climates.
Two of these states—Utah and Rhode Island—enacted significant structural
changes to their pension systems while the two others—New Jersey and
Illinois—enacted more limited, less innovative changes, the paper claims.
McGuinn
believes states should make their complete actuarial payments to pensions every
year. “When payments are skipped or only made in part, unfunded liability can
grow quickly, especially in down markets,” he says. “States should require this, and unions should be prepared and empowered to sue when this does not happen.”
McGuinn also suggests states “gather and disseminate the hard data”—they should
provide data on plan health and more accurate cost projections with more
realistic assumptions. “Communicate and educate,” he says. “It is
difficult to impress upon leaders that liabilities of future years must be
addressed today, especially when it causes financial pain now.” He adds that
states need to take this information to the public.
He
suggests states sell the need for pension reform to teachers and other workers,
telling them that the pain now will mean sustained benefits in the future, and
impaired benefits hurt their ability to recruit the needed work force. “Pension
changes should be framed as ultimately in the best interests of pension
participants, relative to the consequences of the pension plans getting to the
point where they can’t meet their obligations,” he says.
States
should focus on advocacy groups for more broad school reform, for
example, and establish a competing group to unions, which can take the message to workers about why reforms are needed.
McGuinn
also told event attendees states should anticipate legal challenges. The U.S.
and states give a high level of protection to contracts; reformers can be
strategic in designing changes that can survive legal challenges.
“Debate
about what kind of system is best for public sector workers and whether changes
for current workers are adequate and fair—there are legitimate concerns that
reforms can affect the lives of workers, but changes are necessary to protect
sustainability. If there are no changes, pensions may become insolvent and it
will affect public services,” McGuinn says. He adds that raising taxes is
possible to address underfunding, but it is politically difficult and, as
was the case in Illinois, may not solve the problem.
“By highlighting how
some states have enacted reform, we can move forward the discussion for all
public pensions,” he concludes.
Mayor
Chuck Reed of San Jose, California, argues for employee choice. He told event
attendees that his city first tried cutting services; it laid off 20% of
employees across all services to try to address liabilities. “The effect of
underfunding was worse than the effect of reform,” he says.
The
city wanted to make sure employees and retirees were paid what they earn, did not
want to file bankruptcy, and wanted to make sure taxpayers got the services
they deserve. So, San Jose gave public employees a choice: They could either
pay an additional 16% through higher contributions or pay cuts and keep the
same benefits, or not pay more and get lower accrual rates and lower cost-of-living
adjustments.
San
Jose is facing lawsuits from this action. Reed says a state constitutional
amendment is needed to allow governments to negotiate changes for contracts. He contends the fundamental problem with DBs is that they are a high risk and high cost
for plan sponsors; the day a government hires an employee, it takes on 70
years of obligations. “The future should be negotiable,” he says.
Reed
feels it is likely that DC plans will take over in the public sector, but he
believes allowing governments to give employees a choice can reduce costs,
enabling them to preserve DBs.
Mark
Dingley, chief legal counsel and chief of staff in Rhode Island’s Treasury
Office, says the legal argument for amending statutes to allow for negotiating
contracts should address the well-being of the state currently and in the future.
“If you say you want to make changes solely for budget reasons, you will lose,”
he says. "If you could break a contract because you can’t pay, you could break
any contract."
He
notes that every pension reform in the U.S. has been challenged legally. Governments
must know the legal precedent before embarking on their own initiative.
One
of Rhode Island’s arguments when proposing pension reform was that paying
45% of salary for retirement benefits limits the ability to hire new employees
and to make pay increases for current workers. Rhode Island has many young teachers on board with its pension reform, because they were not
sure benefits would be there for them in the future, and thus were not sure if they
would continue to teach for long, Dingley explains.
The
state realized it had to establish a legal foundation for proposed changes, Dingley says, “as
soon as you introduce legislation, it becomes an ideological battle between employees
and officials.” He agrees with McGuinn that before governments introduce
legislation, they must put a proposal on the table and discuss it at public
meetings. He also suggests the legislature have a special session for pension
reform. “Budget and pension reform get mixed up, and discussions are so volatile,
nothing gets settled before the regular session ends, so in a special session
more is likely to get done,” he contends.
Rhode
Island has moved to a hybrid plan, which shares risk and mitigates some
risk for employees, Dingley notes. He points out that in many states, public
employees do not get Social Security, so it is important to keep some core DB
benefit.
The papers discussed
during the Brookings event may be downloaded from here.